DATA Download historical data for 20 million indicators using your browser. Already a user? The annual inflation rate in Australia fell to 3. Prices slowed for transport At the same time, cost of communication fell further In contrast, prices went up faster for food 1.
Also, housing prices rose 1. On a quarterly basis, consumer prices went up 0. Quarter-on-quarter, the index rose 0. Inflation Rate in Australia averaged 4. This page provides the latest reported value for - Australia Inflation Rate - plus previous releases, historical high and low, short-term forecast and long-term prediction, economic calendar, survey consensus and news.
Australia Inflation Rate - data, historical chart, forecasts and calendar of releases - was last updated on November of Inflation Rate in Australia is expected to be 3. In the long-term, the Australia Inflation Rate is projected to trend around 2. Trading Economics members can view, download and compare data from nearly countries, including more than 20 million economic indicators, exchange rates, government bond yields, stock indexes and commodity prices.
Features Questions? Contact us Already a Member? It allows API clients to download millions of rows of historical data, to query our real-time economic calendar, subscribe to updates and receive quotes for currencies, commodities, stocks and bonds. Click here to contact us.
They proved unfounded. There are some longer-run structural changes. After the global financial crisis, the effective supply of workers in the global economy grew due to demographic factors and the re-engagement of China. This has led some commentators to talk about overheating. Read more: What's in the CPI and what does it actually measure? But now the emergence of the more contagious Delta strain has seen a new round of lockdowns. The Australian economy is likely to contract in the September quarter, making our recovery look W-shaped rather than V-shaped as it did.
A big rise in inflation is unlikely unless wages grow strongly. There is no sign of this. Contrary to some claims , the Reserve Bank has not promised to keep interest rates on hold at 0. It is possible to buy indexed government bonds. Rents and dividends also tend to rise with inflation, meaning houses and shares have proved reasonable inflation hedges in the past.
Inflation-targeting countries have generally attempted to build the credibility of the inflation targets by adopting measures to hold the central bank accountable for the inflation outcomes.
In many cases, the accountability has provided an appropriate offset to the increased instrument independence that many central banks have obtained under this framework. In other words, the increased responsibility chat the central bank obtained for achieving desired inflation outcomes came with greater accountability for those outcomes. At the same time, inflation-targeting countries have required central banks to be more transparent about the conduct or monetary policy, so that both the government and the public can monitor their performance and more readily hold them accountable.
Some countries have gone further than Australia in emphasizing accountability and transparency. In particular, New Zealand and the United Kingdom have published regular reports on monetary policy that include official forecasts of quarterly inflation over a two- to three-year horizon. In both cases, the forecasts have helped to signal the path of projected inflation consistent with achieving the objective.
The Reserve Rank does not publish detailed forecasts of inflation or output because the authorities are concerned that the lack of precision in the forecasts and the unpredictable nature of prices could lead to large forecasting errors and thereby undermine the credibility of the bank. In part, the United Kingdom has attempted to address similar concerns by publishing the forecasts complete with confidence ranges.
Instead, the current practice is for the bank to make statements about the outlook for inflation in broad terms without providing details of the quarterly track.
The New Zealand framework incorporates a more transparent and immediate degree of accountability than in Australia and other inflation-targeting countries. If the Governor fails to achieve the targets, he risks losing tenure of his position.
Walsh argues that this may be close to the optimal contract for a central bank governor. McCallum , however, is skeptical that the contract eliminates the inflation bias, because the government has the same incentive not to enforce the contract as identified for the central bank in the inflation bias literature discussed earlier.
In Australia, the tenure of the Governor is not explicitly tied to inflation performance. Nevertheless, performance on the inflation front would no doubt be taken into consideration in any decision to reappoint the Governor once the seven-year term is complete. Furthermore, given the more medium-term focus of the inflation target, the Governor could not be held accountable for inflation outcomes over a shorter period, unless inflation was clearly inconsistent with the medium-term target.
Australian financial markets have been quick to react to news concerning the outlook for inflation, which has put public pressure on the bank to take appropriate action.
Since monetary policy affects economic activity and inflation with long lags, and knowledge of the transmission mechanism is imperfect, the Reserve Bank takes a forward-looking approach and relies on multiple indicators to evaluate the inflation outlook. The bank continually assesses monetary conditions by tracking indicators of future trends in inflation and economic activity, such as wages, capacity utilization, the yield curve, movements in asset prices, market or survey-based expectations of inflation, indicators of the fiscal stance, and financial aggregates.
Based on its evaluation of the inflation outlook, the bank can choose a time path for the official cash interest rate target the main monetary policy instrument in Australia , which results in a forecast of future inflation conditional on the policy setting, and based on an informed judgment that is consistent with achieving the inflation target.
Given that the horizon for achieving the target is not precisely defined, and given that the decision-making process involves assessing current and future inflationary trends and comparing this with the target, the process leaves room for discretion. In turn, such discretionary action will affect the credibility of the target, therefore underlying the importance of transparency and openness in the conduct of monetary policy.
Therefore, success of the framework can be assessed in large part by analyzing inflation performance and the indicators of credibility, such as inflationary expectations. Initially, the adoption of inflation targeting did not appear to enhance the credibility of the Reserve Bank, as inflationary expectations, which were at historically low levels, did not fall further in and Box 5.
This may have been because the inflation-targeting framework had not yet been tested in Australia or in other countries over a full business cycle. Moreover, concerns about the flexible nature of the target, particularly the absence of limits on the extent or duration of deviations from the target range, may have made the target less credible.
More important, given the long history of high inflation in Australia, it is likely that inflationary expectations would only be reduced to levels consistent with the inflation target once a sustained track record of low inflation was achieved.
Recent actions by the Reserve Bank have helped build the credibility of the inflation target. In late , the bank reacted to strong economic growth that threatened achievement of the inflation target by tightening monetary policy the official cash rate was raised by basis points.
As a result, the bank was successful in limiting the extent and duration of the deviation of underlying inflation above 3 percent—the upper end of the target range.
By December , annual underlying inflation had fallen to 1. Inflationary expectations in Australia have fallen markedly over the past 10 years. The differential between the CPI indexed and non-indexed year bonds a proxy for financial-market inflation expectations over the next decade fell from about 8 percent in the late s to about percent in — By the end of , the differential stood at slightly more than 2 percent.
Financial-market economists surveyed by the Reserve Bank just after the release of the December quarter CPI figure had a median forecast of underlying inflation for the year to June of 1. Business-sector inflationary expectations have been somewhat higher than financial-market expectations. The maintenance of low inflation in the past four years has reduced the costs associated with inflation.
One of the most widely recognized costs of inflation in Australia is the incentive that inflation and the tax and accounting systems create for investment in property as discussed in Chapter 2.
This is evident from the strong growth of private investment in dwellings and other construction in the s, a period when inflation averaged about 8 percent Figure 5. In the current economic expansion, however, private investment has been more concentrated on plant and equipment rather than dwelling and other construction.
The shift toward more productive plant and equipment investment may have been due, in part at least, to the lower level of inflation in the s and is likely to be beneficial for medium-term economic growth. It is not yet clear whether the relatively flexible approach to inflation targeting is preferable to the more rigid approach taken in other countries, particularly New Zealand. The rationale for adopting inflation targeting discussed earlier would argue that regimes with a well-defined and transparent target, and a central bank that is held accountable for inflation outcomes, would gain in terms of enhanced credibility and lower costs of maintaining inflation, when compared with the Australian approach.
Since the adoption of the target in , Australia has achieved inflation outcomes consistent with the target and slightly below the average for other inflation-targeting countries, while real GDP growth has been stronger and its variability lower than in other inflation-targeting countries Table 5. Australia has maintained inflation at low levels in recent years, but was this because of inflation targeting per se or would an alternative monetary policy approach have worked just as well?
This question is difficult to answer, as it is not possible to assess the counterfactual. Nonetheless, a comparison of Australia and other inflation-targeting countries with non-inflation-targeting countries can help assess the performance of inflation targeting relative to other approaches.
In a recent study, Haldane presents some evidence of a regime shift in the inflation performance of inflation-targeting countries because of the adoption of the targets.
This is based on the observations that mean inflation fell significantly in the inflation targeting countries following the adoption of the targets, and that the fall was greater than in a control group of large non-inflation-targeting countries France, Germany, Italy, Japan, and the United States; see Table 5.
In fact, inflation was lower on average in the s in the inflation-targeting countries than for this control group. Inflation rates are calculated as the year-on-year change in the quarterly index. Haldane also observes that there is little evidence that the mean or variability of output was adversely affected by disinflation in the inflation-targeting countries. In fact, it is quite the contrary for the inflation-targeting countries, as there is evidence that output variability decreased more recently for this group, whereas variability increased for the large non-inflation-targeting countries.
A comparison with an alternative control group of smaller non-inflation-targeting countries Belgium, Denmark, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Norway, Luxembourg, and Portugal also suggests that the inflation-targeting countries were more successful in achieving low inflation. A comparison of Australia with the other country groups suggests that inflation targeting helped achieve a regime shift in inflation in Australia, without costs in terms of greater output variability. Both the mean and variability of underlying CPI inflation in Australia were significantly lower in the period following the introduction of inflation targeting in Furthermore, the mean and variability of inflation following the adoption of the target was lower than that for all other country groups.
The cross-country evidence tends to suggest that the inflation-targeting approach has made a difference, particularly in Australia, without involving excessive real costs.
The experience with the approach, however, has been relatively short. None of the inflation-targeting countries has experienced a full business cycle or a range of shocks, and the true test of the approach will come over time. But the new framework itself will not guarantee maintenance of low inflation. In particular, the authorities will need to make careful use of the flexibility to take countercyclical monetary and fiscal policy measures built into the macroeconomic policy framework, and to ensure that the focus on the medium-term objectives is not lost and that the credibility of the framework is not undermined.
The framework has been successful in maintaining low inflation during an expansionary phase of the cycle, but has not yet faced a contractionary phase. Such a contraction could lead to a potential conflict between the medium-term price stability and full employment objectives of the Reserve Bank, as political pressures to loosen monetary policy for short-term gains come to bear. An inappropriately loose stance of monetary policy in such circumstances may pose a risk for the medium-term inflation objective, given the long lags in the transmission mechanism.
Furthermore, the framework has not yet been tested by a supply-shock with world inflation having been benign in recent years. The framework has gained credibility with the financial markets but inflationary expectations have lagged the actual reduction in inflation, particularly among consumer and business groups, with continuing costs in terms of wage claims and unemployment.
These considerations argue for continued vigilance to build a strong track record of low inflation so as to bring expectations into line with the actual low rates. Barro , Robert J. Calvo , G. Lucas and T. Sargent Allen and Urwin. Costello , The Rt. Crawford , A. Rae , David , Michelle Lloyd , and A. Although the Australian currency was fixed to the United Kingdom pound sterling in the s, it was not devalued with the sterling in From December , the exchange rate was fixed against the U.
Similarly, in the early s, a high wage settlement in the booming metal trade industry set the pace for other wage settlements, and average nonfarm wages increased by almost 50 percent in the three years to end It was announced in the budget speech with major decisions on monetary policy taken by the Monetary Policy Committee of the Cabinet.
The underlying consumer price index CPI is defined as the headline CPI adjusted for special factors that are judged to be either highly volatile or not directly related to excess demand pressures such as changes in mortgage and consumer interest charges and in the prices of publicly provided items.
It was defined by the Australian Treasury and is derived by excluding the following items from the CPI basket: meat and seafood, fresh fruit and vegetables, clothing, government-owned dwelling rents, mortgage interest charges, consumer credit charges, local government rates and charges, household fuel and light, automotive fuel, postal and telephone services, urban transportation fares, tobacco and alcohol, health services, pharmaceuticals, holiday travel and accommodation, and education and child care.
The larger fall in the headline rate was due to a reduction in interest rates. The Australian Bureau of Statistics includes mortgage rates directly in the headline CPI, with a weight of about 6 percent.
Mortgage rates are closely related to short-term interest rates, as most mortgages in Australia are of the floating rate type. As a result, changes in monetary policy tend to have a pronounced effect on the headline CPI. Private sector credit grew by more than percent in the five years to , and this growth occurred despite the relatively firm monetary policy stance. Macfarlane notes that the credit growth was associated with a fall in credit standards in the late s, on the pan: of both lenders and borrowers.
On the part of lenders, credit standards fell because of strong competition among financial institutions as a result of the removal of interest rate ceilings and the entry of new players, particularly foreign banks. Macfarlane argues that this explanation is too simplistic and that a major factor in the credit growth was pent-up demand for credit from businesses responding to the incentive to borrow provided by inflation and the tax deducibility of interest payments.
Alternative approaches to monetary policy, such as monetary or exchange rate targeting, aim to achieve the ultimate objective of price stability by targeting an intermediate variable. A disadvantage of the alternative approaches is that the ultimate objective of price stability is less transparent than with inflation targeting, making it more difficult to assess the performance of monetary policy and there by reducing the accountability for achieving the ultimate objective of price stability.
The target for Spain less than 3 percent by and less than 2 percent from onwards is more comparable with Australia, but given that this is an upper bound with no lower bounds specified , it implies a lower level of targeted inflation than in Australia.
This result is based on an analysis of forecasts of inflation for the full period — Given that the variance of inflation has fallen as the mean inflation rate has fallen over this period, forecasting errors are now likely to be lower than in the late s.
This is reflected in somewhat lower forecasting errors reported by Debelle and Stevens for the period —94 than for the late s. Debelle and Stevens note that the longest period of relatively stable low inflation in recent history occurred in Germany from —71, when average inflation was 2. Year-on-year underlying inflation peaked in this period at 3. However, year-on-year headline inflation reached a peak of 5. By the end of , underlying inflation had been reduced to 1. While it is much less volatile than the headline rate, the underlying measure has followed the same medium-term trend over the cycle as the headline index.
For instance, over the 10 years to the end of , the underlying measure increased by In New Zealand, the adoption of inflation targeting was accompanied by legislating the goal of price stability as the prime objective of an independent and accountable central bank.
In Spain, the adoption of targets was also accompanied by a greater degree of independence for the central bank. In the United Kingdom, greater central bank independence was adopted in , several years after the adoption of inflation targeting. In the case of a demand shock—for example, an unanticipated increase in aggregate demand—the monetary policy response of raising interest rates would serve the dual purposes of slowing activity and lowering inflation.
However, in the case of a supply shock—for example, an unanticipated fall in aggregate supply—monetary policy aimed at dampening inflation would tend to exacerbate the shortfall in output. The headline CPI fell by 0. These were the lowest headline CPI inflation rates since June , and were lower than the underlying CPI inflation mainly because of a fall in mortgage interest rates which are included in the headline measure but excluded from the underlying measure.
The Australian real long-term interest rates are calculated here using the year government bond yield less the annual underlying CPI inflation rate; however, use of the current annual inflation rate may mean the measure of real interest rates is inappropriate as it does not necessarily reflect inflationary expectations. Yields on CPI-indexed bonds which by definition need no adjustment for expected inflation suggest somewhat lower real interest rates of about 4 percent at the end of These smaller countries may be a better control group than the large non-inflation-targeting countries, because they are small and experienced high inflation in the s, similar to many of the inflation-targeting countries.
All Rights Reserved. Topics Business and Economics. Banks and Banking. Corporate Finance. Corporate Governance. Corporate Taxation. Economic Development. Economic Theory. Economics: General. Environmental Economics. Exports and Imports. Finance: General.
Financial Risk Management. Foreign Exchange. Industries: Automobile. Industries: Energy. Industries: Fashion and Textile. Industries: Financial Services. Industries: Food. Industries: General. Industries: Hospital,Travel and Tourism. Industries: Information Technololgy. Industries: Manufacturing. Industries: Service. Information Management.
International Economics. International Taxation. Investments: Bonds. Investments: Commodities. Investments: Derivatives. Investments: Energy. Investments: Futures. Investments: General.
Investments: Metals. Investments: Mutual Funds. Investments: Options. Investments: Stocks. Islamic Banking and Finance. Money and Monetary Policy. Natural Resource Extraction. Personal Finance -Taxation.
Production and Operations Management. Public Finance. Real Estate. Sustainable Development. Urban and Regional. Cloud Computing. Computer Science. Data Processing. Data Transmission Systems. Internet: General. Management Information Systems.
Web: Social Media. Health and Fitness. Diet and Nutrition. Diseases: Contagious. Diseases: Respiratory. Business and Financial. Health Policy. Natural Resources. Environmental Conservation and Protection. Natural Disasters. Political Science. Environmental Policy. Social Services and Welfare. Civics and Citizenship. National and International Security. Political Economy. Social Science. Women's Studies. Emigration and Immigration. Gender Studies.
Poverty and Homelessness. Technology and Engineering. Mobile and Wireless Communications.
0コメント